Thursday, July 18, 2019
Perfect Competition
Perfect Competition Inà economic theory,à perfect competitionà describes markets such that no participants are large enough to have theà market powerà to set the price of a homogeneous product. Because the conditions for perfect competition are strict, there are few if any perfectly competitive markets. Still, buyers and sellers in someà auction-type markets, say forà commoditiesà or some financial assets, may approximate the concept. Perfect competition serves as a benchmark against which to measure real-life andà imperfectly competitiveà markets.Generally, a perfectly competitive market exists when every participant is a ââ¬Å"price takerâ⬠, and no participant influences the price of the product it buys or sells. Specific characteristics may include: * Infinite buyers and sellersà ââ¬â An infinite number of consumers with the willingness and ability to buy the product at a certain price, and infinite producers with the willingness and ability to supp ly the product at a certain price. * Zero entry and exit barriersà ââ¬â A lack of entry and exit barriers makes it extremely easy to enter or exit a perfectly competitive market. Perfect factor mobilityà ââ¬â In the long runà factors of productionà are perfectly mobile, allowing free long term adjustments to changing market conditions. * Perfect informationà ââ¬â All consumers and producers are assumed to have perfect knowledge of price, utility, quality and production methods of products. * Zero transaction costsà ââ¬â Buyers and sellers do not incur costs in making an exchange of goods in a perfectly competitive market. * Profit maximizationà ââ¬â Firms are assumed to sell where marginal costs meet marginal revenue, where the most profit is generated. Homogenous productsà ââ¬â The qualities and characteristics of a market good or service do not vary between different suppliers. * Non-increasing returns to scaleà ââ¬â The lack of increa sing returns to scale (or economies of scale) ensures that there will always be a sufficient number of firms in the industry. * Property rightsà ââ¬â Well defined property rights determine what may be sold, as well as what rights are conferred on the buyer. In the short run, perfectly-competitive markets are notà productively efficientà as output will not occur where marginal cost is equal to average cost (MC=AC).They areà allocatively efficient, as output will always occur whereà marginal costà is equal toà marginal revenue(MC=MR). In the long run, perfectly competitive markets are both allocatively and productively efficient. In perfect competition, any profit-maximizing producer faces aà market priceà equal to itsà marginal costà (P=MC). This implies that a factor's price equals the factor's marginal revenue product. It allows for derivation of the supply curve on which the neoclassical approach is based. This is also the reason why ââ¬Å"a monopoly doe s not have a supply curveâ⬠.The abandonment of price taking creates considerable difficulties for the demonstration of a general equilibrium except under other, very specific conditions such as that of monopolistic competition. By definition a perfectly competitive market is one in which no single firm has to influence either the equilibrium price of the market or the the total quantity supplied in the market. Thus, a firm operating in a competitive market has no incentive to supply at a price lower than market equilibrium price, as it can sell all it wants to supply at equilibrium.At the same time, the firm cannot sell at price higher than the market price, because it will be able find no buyers at that price, and its sales volume will drop down to zero. Thus, a firm operating in perfectly competitive market has to accept whatever is the market equilibrium price, and therefore it is called a price taker. In contrast, a monopoly firm is the only supplier in the market and there fore has full control over the market prices and total market supplies.Therefore, a firm operating in a monopoly market fixes its price in such a way that for the quantity demanded by customers at that market price the marginal revenue of the firm is equal to its marginal costs. In this way way it decides the market price as well as the total quantity if a commodity supplied in the market, and therefore it is called a price maker. Imperfect Competition Inà economic theory,à imperfect competitionà is the competitive situation in any market where the sellers in the market sell different/dissimilar of goods, (haterogenous) that does not meet the conditions of perfect competition.Forms of imperfect competition include: * Monopoly, in which there is only one seller of a good. * Oligopoly, in which there are few sellers of a good. * Monopolistic competition, in which there are many sellers producing highly differentiated goods. * Monopsony, in which there is only one buyer of a good . * Oligopsony, in which there are few buyers of a good. * Information asymmetryà when one competitor has the advantage of more or better information. There may also be imperfect competition due to a time lag in a market. An example is the ââ¬Å"jobless recoveryâ⬠.There are many growth opportunities available after a recession, but it takes time for employers to react, leading to highà unemployment. High unemployment decreases wages, which makes hiring more attractive, but it takes time for new jobs to be created. A type ofà market that does not operate under the rigid rules of perfect competition. Perfect competition implies an industry or market in which no one supplier can influence prices, barriers to entry and exit are small, all suppliers offer the same goods, there are a large number ofà suppliers and buyers, and information on pricing and process is readily available.Forms of imperfect competition include monopoly, oligopoly, monopolistic competition, monopson y and oligopsony. Pure Competition Pure Competitionà is a market situation where there is a large number of independent sellers offering identical products. Pure competition is a term for an industry where competition isstagnant and relatively non competitive. Companies within the pure competition category have little control of price or distribution of product. Advertising, market research, and product development play a very little role in these companies/industries.Aà marketà characterized by a largeà numberà of independentà sellersà of standardizedà products, freeà flowà of information, andà free entryà andà exit. Each seller is a ââ¬Å"price takerâ⬠rather than a ââ¬Å"price makerâ⬠. Also sometimes referred to asà perfect competition,à pureà competitionà is a situation in which the market for a product is populated with so many consumers and producers that no one entity has the ability to influence the price of the product sufficien tly to cause a fluctuation.Within this type of market setting, sellers are considered to be price takers, indicating that they are not in a position to set the price for their products outside a certain range, given the fact that so many other producers are active within the market. At the same time, consumers have little influence over the prices offered by the producers, since there is no singular group of consumers that dominates the demand. In reality,à pureà competitionà is moreà theoryà than actual fact.While there are rare situations in which a marketplace functions withà pureà competitionà for a short period of time, the situation normally shifts as various factors change the stalemate created by a multiplicity of sellers and buyers. This is often due to the somewhat stringent set of factors that must be present in order for theà competitionà to be considered perfect orà pure. There are several essential characteristics that defineà pureà competitio n. One has to do with the balance of buyers to sellers.When there is an infinite number of buyers who are willing to purchase the products offered for sale by an infinite number of producers, at a certain price, the opportunity for anyone to take actions that shift the market price is extremely limited. The price remains more or less the same, and the same number of buyers purchase the products from the same range of producers. Withà pureà competition, sellers can easily exit or enter the marketplace, without creating any undue influence on the price. Consumers continue to make purchases at the same rate, even if two companies leave the market and only one new one enters.The collective producers who are still in the market simply continue to produce enough products to meet consumer demand, without a shift in market price. Businesses engaged in aà pureà competitionà market usually structure production so that they incur marginal costs at a level where they can earn the most profit. When the product line is homogeneous, this means the products produced are essentially the same as the product line produced by otherà suppliersà in the marketplace. Assuming the costs are in line withmarginal revenue, the business can generate a consistent profit for as long as the condition ofà pureà competitionà is present in the market.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.